Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-gtxcr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T00:35:42.167Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Trade Openness, Country Size and Economic Volatility: The Compensation Hypothesis Revisited

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 January 2017

Ian Down*
Affiliation:
University of Tennessee, Knoxville

Abstract

A prominent variant of the compensation hypothesis rests on the premise that increased trade exposure heightens domestic economic volatility, prompting demands for compensation via generous systems of transfers and services. Economic theory suggests that because the expansion of international trade entails integration into larger, deeper, more stable markets, and may entail risk diversification, it may actually promote rather than reduce stability. By the same token, however, economic theory also suggests that smaller economies should experience greater levels of volatility than larger economies, and thus also greater levels of insecurity. The evidence presented here suggests that the level of domestic economic volatility in the developed economies, during the latter half of the twentieth century, may indeed have been driven by the size and depth of markets. And critically, for these countries international trade integration may have eased rather than accentuated domestic economic volatility.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © V.K. Aggarwal 2007 and published under exclusive license to Cambridge University Press 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adserà, Alícia and Boix, Carles. 2002. “Trade, Democracy, and the Size of the Public Sector: The Political Underpinnings of Openness.” International Organization 56 (2): 229262.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Spolaore, Enrico. 2003. The Size of Nations Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Wacziarg, Romain. 1998. “Openness, Country size and Government.” Journal of Public Economics 69: 305–22.Google Scholar
Aukrust, Odd. 1977. “Inflation in the Open Economy.” In Worldwide Inflation: Theory and Recent Experience, edited by Krause, Lawrence B., and Salant, Walter S. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, and Katz, Jonathan N. 1995. “What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series–Cross-Section Data.” American Political Science Review Volume 89: 634647.Google Scholar
Beck, Nathaniel, and Katz, Jonathan N. 2004. “Time-Series-Cross-Section Issues: Dynamics.” Paper presented at the 2004 Annual Meeting of the Society for Political Methodology, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Brambor, Thomas, Roberts Clark, William, and Golder, Matt. 2006. “Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses.” Political Analysis 14: 6382.Google Scholar
Cameron, David R. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis.” American Political Science Review Volume 72: 12431261.Google Scholar
Czada, Roland. 1988. “Bestimmungsfaktoren und Genese politischer Gewerkschaftseinbindung.” In Staatstatigkeit: International und historisch vergleichende Analysen, edited by Schmidt, Manfred G. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.Google Scholar
Gleditsch, Kristian. 2002. “Expanded Trade and GDP DataJournal of Conflict Resolution 46: 712–24.Google Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, and Stephens, John D. 2001. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, Ragin, Charles, Stephens, John D, Brady, David, and Beckfield, Jason, Comparative Welfare States Data Set. Northwestern University, University of North Carolina, Duke University and Indiana University, 2004.Google Scholar
Iversen, Torben. 2001. “The Dynamics of Welfare State Expansion.” In The New Politics of the Welfare State, edited by Pierson, Paul. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Iversen, Torben, and Cusack, Thomas R. 2000. “The Causes of Welfare State Expansion: Deindustrialization or Globalization?World Politics 52: 313–49.Google Scholar
Katzenstein, Peter J. 1985. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Kono, Daniel Y, and Love, Greg. 2007. “Who Rides the Storm? Political Institutions and Trade AdjustmentBusiness and Politics, Volume 9: Issue 1, Article 2.Google Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar. 1975. “Business Cycles, Politics, and International Economic Dependence.” Skandinaviska Enskilden Bank Quarterly Review 2: 5368.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 1998. “Why Do Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?Journal of Political Economy 106: 9971032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerrard. 1982. “International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order.” International Organization 36 (2): 379402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schulze, Gunther G, and Ursprung, Heinrich W. 1999. “Globalization of the Economy and the Nation State.” The World Economy Volume 22, Issue 3: 295352.Google Scholar
Stephens, John. 1979. The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephens, John. 2000. “Economic Internationalization and Domestic Compensation: Northwestern Europe in Comparative Perspective.” Unpublished manuscript, UNC-Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill NC.Google Scholar
Swank, Duane. 2002. Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar