Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T19:41:31.277Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Global Migration and Political Regime Type: A Democratic Disadvantage

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 March 2012

Abstract

An indicator of globalization is the growing number of humans crossing national borders. In contrast to explanations for flows of goods and capital, migration research has concentrated on unilateral movements to rich democracies. This focus ignores the bilateral determinants of migration and stymies empirical and theoretical inquiry. The theoretical insights proposed here show how the regime type of both sending and receiving countries influences human migration. Specifically, democratic regimes accommodate fewer immigrants than autocracies and democracies enable emigration while autocracies prevent exit. The mechanisms for this divergence are a function of both micro-level motivations of migrants and institutional constraints on political leaders. Global bilateral migration data and a statistical method that captures the higher-order dependencies in network data are employed in this article.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Department of Political Science, University of Toronto; Department of Political Science, Penn State University (email: xuc11@psu.edu); and Department of Political Science, State University of New York, respectively. The authors are listed in alphabetical order, and equal authorship is implied. Previous versions of the article were presented at the 2008 annual meetings of the American Political Science Association and the International Political Economy Society, and the Annual Political Networks Conference in 2010. We would like to thank John Ahlquist, David Bearce, Bela Hovy, Mark Kayser, Jeffrey Kopstein, David Leblang, Douglas Massey, Helen Milner, Phil Triadafilopoulos, Hugh Ward, Michael Ward, Anton Westveld, Erik Wibbels, two anonymous reviewers and Journal Editor Kristian Gleditsch for their helpful comments. Finally, the authors would like to thank Christopher Parsons, Ronald Skeldon, Terrie Walmsley and L. Alan Winters for assembling the migration data upon which a portion of the dataset is based. Replication files and an online appendix with more robustness checks are posted on the authors’ websites.

References

1 Hollifield, James F., ‘Migration, Trade, and the Nation-State: The Myth of Globalization’, UCLA Journal of International Law and Foreign Affairs, 3 (1998), 595636Google Scholar

2 ‘Briefing Migration: A turning tide?’ The Economist (26 June 2008), p. 31.

3 Chiswick, Barry R. and Markets’, Timothy J.Hatton, International Migration and the Integration of Labor, in Michael D. Bordo, Alan M. Taylor and Jeffrey G. Williamson eds, Globalization in Historical Perspective (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003)Google Scholar

4 Mirilovic, Nikola, ‘Explaining the Politics of Immigration: Dictatorship, Development, and Defense’, Comparative Politics, 42 (2010), 273292CrossRefGoogle Scholar

5 Cornelius, Wayne and Rosenblum, Marc, ‘Immigration and Politics’, Annual Review of Political Science, 8 (2005), 99119CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6 Ellermann, Antje, States Against Migrants: Deportation in Germany and the United States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 Massey, Douglas S., ‘International Migration at the Dawn of the Twenty-First Century: The Role of the State’, Population and Development Review, 25 (1999), 303322CrossRefGoogle Scholar

8 Missing data reduce the sample used in the subsequent analysis to 148 countries.

9 Mansfield, Edward D.Milner, Helen V. and Rosendorff, B. Peter, ‘Why Democracies Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements’, International Organization, 56 (2002), 477513CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Milner, Helen V. and Kubota, Keiko, ‘Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries’, International Organization, 59 (2005), 107143CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10 Leblang, DavidFitzgerald, Jennifer and Teets, Jessica, ‘Defying the Law of Gravity: The Political Economy of International Migration’ (Working Paper: Department of Political Science, University of Colorado, 2007)Google Scholar

11 Douglas Massey et al., ‘Theories of International Migration: A Review and Appraisal’, Population and Development Review, 19 (1993), 431466CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 Massey et al., ‘Theories of International Migration’.

13 Borjas, George J., Friends or Strangers: The Impact of Immigrants on the U.S. Economy (New York: Basic Books, 1990)Google Scholar

Massey, Douglas, Arango, JoaquinHugo, Graeme and Kouaouci, Ali, Worlds in Motion: Understanding International Migration at the End of the Millennium (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005)Google Scholar

Harris, John R. and Todaro, Michael P., ‘Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two-Sector Analysis’, American Economic Review, 60 (1970), 126142Google Scholar

14 Massey, ‘International Migration at the Dawn of the Twenty-First Century’, pp. 308–309.

15 Hatton, Timothy J. and Williamson, Jeffrey G., The Age of Mass Migration: Causes and Economic Impact (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Nations, United, UNHCR: 2006 Global Trends (New York: United Nations Publications, 2006)Google Scholar

17 Gibney, Matthew J., The Ethics and Politics of Asylum: Liberal Democracy and the Response to Refugees (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

18 Joppke, Christian, Challenge to the Nation-state: Immigration in Western Europe and the United States (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

19 Jacobson, David, Rights Across Borders: Immigration and the Decline of Citizenship (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1996)Google Scholar

Bauböck, Rainer, Transnational Citizenship: Membership Rights In International Migration (Aldershot, Surrey: Edward Elgar, 1994)Google Scholar

Soysal, Yasemin, The Limits of Citizenship: Migrants and Postnational Membership in Europe (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994)Google Scholar

20 Mirilovic, ‘Explaining the Politics of Immigration’.

21 Levitsky, Steven and Way, Lucan, Competitive Authoritarianism: The Origins and Evolution of Hybrid Regimes in the Post-Cold War Era (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

22 Massey et al., ‘Theories of International Migration’, p. 36Google Scholar

23 Mirilovic, ‘Explaining the Politics of Immigration’. We also expand the argument to the role of regime type on determining exit restrictions.

24 Messina, Anthony M. and Lahav, Gallya, The Migration Reader: Exploring Politics And Policies (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 2005)Google Scholar

25 Fetzer, Joel, Public Attitudes Toward Immigration in the United States, France, and Germany (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000)Google Scholar

Hansen, Randall, Citizenship and Immigration in Post-War Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Guiraudon, Virginie, ‘European Integration and Migration Policy: Vertical Policy-making as Venue Shopping’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 38 (2000), 251271CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Kessler, Alan and Freeman, Gary, ‘Public Opinion in the EU on Immigration from Outside the Community’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 43 (2005), 825850CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Simon, Rita and Alexander, Susan, The Ambivalent Welcome: Print Media, Public Opinion and Immigration (Westport, Conn.: Praeger, 1993)Google Scholar

26 Cornelius and Rosenblum, ‘Immigration and Politics’, p. 104

27 Hollifield, James, Immigrants, Markets, and States: The Political Economy of Postwar Europe (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1992)Google Scholar

Freeman, Gary, ‘Winners and Losers: Politics and the Costs and Benefits of Migration’, in Anthony Messina, ed., West European Immigration and Immigrant Policy in the New Century (Westport, Conn.: Praeger, 2002), pp. 7796Google Scholar

28 Joppke, Christian, Immigration and the Nation-State: The United States, Germany, and Great Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

29 Lahav, Gallya, ‘Public Opinion Toward Immigration in the European Union: Does It Matter?’ Comparative Political Studies, 37 (2004), 11511183CrossRefGoogle Scholar

30 Guiraudon, ‘European Integration and Migration Policy’.

31 Massey, ‘International Migration at the Dawn of the Twenty-First Century’, p. 318Google Scholar

32 Messina, Anthony M. and Lahav, Gallya eds, The Migration Reader: Exploring Politics and Policies (New York: Croom Helm, 2002)Google Scholar

33 United Nations, ‘International Migration Report 2002’.

34 Chandler, Andrea, Institutions of Isolation: Border Controls in the Soviet Union and its Successor States (Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 U.S. Department of State, 2009 Country Reports on Human Rights Practices, technical Report (http://www.state.gov/g/drl/rls/hrrpt/2009/index.htm: Report, 2010).

36 U.S. Department of State, 2009 Country Reports on Human Rights Practices.

37 U.S. Department of State, 2009 Country Reports on Human Rights Practices.

38 Linneman, Hans, An Econometric Study of International Trade Flows (Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company, 1966)Google Scholar

39 Sjaastad, Larry A., ‘The Costs and Returns of Human Migration’, Journal of Political Economy, 70 (1962), 8093CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Ranis, Gustav and Fei, John C. H., ‘A Theory of Economic Development’, American Economic Review, 51 (1961), 533565Google Scholar

Lewis, W. Arthur, ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor’, Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 22 (1954), 139191CrossRefGoogle Scholar

40 Massey et al., ‘Theories of International Migration’.

41 Messina, Anthony and Lahav, Gallyaeds, The Migration Reader: Exploring Politics and Policies (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Reinner, 2003)Google Scholar

42 Sassen, Saskia, The Mobility of Labor and Capital: A Study in International Investment and Labor Flow (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998)Google Scholar

43 Leblang, Fitzgerald and Teets, Defying the Law of Gravity.

44 Massey et al., Worlds in Motion.

45 Hansen, Randall, ‘Globalization, Embedded Realism and Path Dependence: The Other Immigrants to Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 35 (2002): 259–283CrossRefGoogle Scholar

46 Wallerstein, Immanuel, The Modern World System (New York: Academic Press, 1974)Google Scholar

47 Massey et al., ‘Theories of International Migration’, p. 42Google Scholar

48 Massey et al., ‘Theories of International Migration’, p. 42Google Scholar

49 United Nations. Department of Economic and Social Affairs. Population Division, International Migration Report 2002 (United Nations Publications, April 2003), p. 340.

50 Popfam, Forced Migration Learning Module, technical report, (http://www.columbia.edu/itc/hs/pubhealth/modules/forcedMigration/definitions.html: The Harriet and Robert H. Heilbrunn Department of Population and Family Health, Columbia University Mailman School of Public Health, 2008).

51 Christopher R. Parsons et al., Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants, T13, Working Paper (Development Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation and Poverty, 2005).

52 All statistical work was conducted using R (R Development Core Team, R: A language and environment for statistical computing [Vienna, Austria: R Foundation for Statistical Computing, 2008]).

53 We use three-letter acronyms to represent countries in the figures in this article. Please see Appendix B for corresponding country names.

54 Parsons et al., Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants.

55 United Nations, International Migration Flows to and from Selected Countries (New York: United Nations Publication, 2005).

56 United Nations, International Migration Flows to and from Selected Countries.

57 Parsons et al., Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants.

58 United Nations, International Migration Flows to and from Selected Countries.

59 Parsons et al., Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants.

60 CIA, The World Factbook (Washington, D.C.: Central Intelligence Agency, accessed: 03/22/2006: http://www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook/fields/2122.html, 2004).

61 Rose, Andrew K., ‘Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade?’ American Economic Review, 94 (2004), 98114CrossRefGoogle Scholar

62 Ray Brownrigg, Maps: Draw Geographical Maps, R package version 2.0-40 (original S code by Richard A. Becker and Allan R. Wilks; enhancements by Thomas P. Minka., 2008)Google Scholar

63 We operationalize the population size variable as the average population size (logged) of the country in the ten years previous to 2000.

64 These data are from http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm. We operationalize GDP per capita and polity as the minimum values of the country in the ten years previous to 2000. However, the empirical findings do not change if we operationalize these two variables as the mean values in the previous ten years.

65 Philip Nel and Marjolein Righarts, ‘Natural Disasters and the Risk of Violent Civil Conflict’, International Studies Quarterly, 52 (2008), 159–85.

66 We gratefully received a replication dataset from Philip Nel and Marjolein Righarts of the University of Otago that provides data on natural disasters.

67 Nils Peter Gleditsch et al., ‘Armed Conflict 1946–2001: A New Dataset’, Journal of Peace Research, 39 (2002), 615637CrossRefGoogle Scholar

68 Parsons et al., Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants.

69 Hoff, Peter D., ‘Bilinear Mixed Effects Models for Dyadic Data’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 100 (2005), 286295CrossRefGoogle Scholar

70 We model the random effects as being multivariate normal. In this way, we can estimate their covariance structure: $\sigma _{a}^{2} $ is the variance of the sender random effects and $\sigma _{b}^{2} $ the variance of the receiver random effects. Additionally, the covariance between these two components is given by ${{\sigma }_{ab}} $.

71 Ward, Michael D. and Hoff, Peter D., ‘Persistent Patterns of International Commerce’, Journal of Peace Research, 44 (2007), 157175CrossRefGoogle Scholar

72 Ward, Michael D.Siverson, Randolph M. and Cao, Xun, ‘Disputes, Democracies, and Dependencies: A Re-examination of the Kantian Peace’, American Journal of Political Science, 51 (2007), 583601CrossRefGoogle Scholar

73 Wasserman, Stanley and Faust, Katherine, Social Network Analysis: Methods and Applications (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

74 Hoff, Peter D.Raftery, Adrian E. and Handcock, Mark S., ‘Latent Space Approaches to Social Network Analysis’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 97 (2002), 10901098CrossRefGoogle Scholar

75 See Hoff, ‘Bilinear Mixed Effects Models for Dyadic Data’, for the detailed procedure of Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) estimation. We use empirical Bayes priors with a glm-type approach.

76 Appendix A provides an assessment of the predictive power of the model.

77 Lewer, Joshua and Hendrik Van den, Berg, ‘A Gravity Model of Immigration’, Economics Letters, 99 (2008), 164–167CrossRefGoogle Scholar

78 Haynes, Kingsley E. and Fotheringham, A. Stewart, Gravity and Spatial Interaction Models (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1984)Google Scholar

Sen, Ashish and Smith, Tony E., Gravity Models of Spatial Interaction Behavior (New York: Springer, 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Wilson, Alan G., ‘A Statistical Theory of Spatial Distribution Models’, Transportation Research, 1 (1967), 253269CrossRefGoogle Scholar

79 Lewer and Berg, ‘A Gravity Model of Immigration’.

80 Hein de Haas, International Migration, Remittances and Development: Myths and Fact, Global Migration Perspectives No. 30 (Global Commission on International Migration, 2005), see http://www.gcim.org.

81 Our findings do not change when we replace civil conflict with political terror or low intensity conflict. The results indicate that low-intensity conflicts and political terror do not lead to emigration.

82 A similar story can be told for the top ten countries ranked by mean random sender country effects: Lebanon (1.40), Guyana (1.20), Cape Verde (1.05), Morocco (1.05), Russia (1.04), Mexico (0.96), Congo (0.92), New Zealand (0.87), Eritrea (0.85) and Kazakhstan (0.78). After controlling for the effects of dyadic and sender and receiver specific covariates, there are still factors that we do not know that make these countries stand out as the main senders of migration.

83 Note that we choose not to display the axes in the figure, because there is no substantive meaning for the x-axis and y-axis in a figure after multidimensional scaling – the axes only represent relative positions for countries in the policy space and one can simply rotate the figure (therefore having different values for the axes) and keep the same configuration for the countries in the space.

84 Parsons et al., Quantifying the International Bilateral Movements of Migrants.

85 These fourteen countries include Bahrain, Iran, Israel, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Oman, Saudi Arabia, Syria, Yemen, Morocco, Tunisia, Algeria and Egypt. Notice that not all these countries are oil-rich countries. Some of them, for example, those in North Africa, are important sending countries of immigrants to the oil-rich countries in the region.

86 We would like to thank an anonymous reviewer for this idea.

87 Gelman, Andrew and Hill, Jennifer, Data Analysis Using Regression and Multilevel/Hierarchical Models (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2007)Google Scholar

88 Paul Smith, ‘Anti-immigrant xenophobia around the world’, New York Times, 14 February 1996.

89 Deutsche Bank Research, ‘International Migration: Who, Where and Why?’

90 Messina and Lahav, The Migration Reader.

91 De Haas, International Migration, Remittances and Development.

92 Leblang, David, ‘Familiarity Breeds Investment: Diaspora Networks and International Investment’, American Political Science Review 104 (2010), 584–600CrossRefGoogle Scholar

93 Hollifield, ‘Migration, Trade, and the Nation-State’.