Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-mp689 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T06:35:56.570Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Country Matters: The Growth of Political Stability a Quarter-Century On

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 July 2014

Get access

Extract

Like Professor Roberts, I, too, think that re-evaluation of J. H. Plumb's The Growth of Political Stability, 1625-1725 poses interesting questions. However, unlike Professor Roberts, I do not think that the scholarship of the past quarter-century has undermined the foundations of Plumb's book. In large part, our assessments differ because we interpret Plumb's book differently. Roberts questions Plumb's identification of the structures that stabilized English politics; but Roberts does not present Plumb's diagnosis of what had been destabilizing English politics, and why. I consider that diagnosis the foundation of Plumb's book, for I read Plumb as arguing that the government of independent gentlemen—even if it be government by independent gentlemen—is no easy matter. How to govern effectively without arousing the ire of those whose autonomy effective central government would inevitably infringe? How to avoid attracting the enmity of powerful landowners, of merchants with power of their own, and of a populace with an experience of rebellion egregious even for seventeenth-century Europe? Roberts does not argue with Plumb's diagnosis of the causes of instability. However, his own solution to that problem implies that Plumb's book is ill-founded, for Roberts never mentions the problems intrinsic to governing the independent. Instead, he proposes that England achieved stability because English politicians elaborated constitutional conventions that subordinated the monarch to Parliament, and because the Church of England no longer had to fear for its existence. Roberts is dancing to a Whig beat, but Plumb played a Country tune.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © North American Conference on British Studies 1993

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 SirNamier, Lewis, “Monarchy and the Party System,” in Personalities and Powers (New York, 1955), pp. 25-26, 28, 34Google Scholar, and ibid., “Country Gentlemen in Parliament,” pp. 59-77.

2 Fletcher, Anthony, Reform in the Provinces: The Government of Stuart England (New Haven, 1986), pp. 4344Google Scholar; Holmes, Clive, “The County Community in Stuart Historiography,” Journal of British Studies 19 (1980): 5455CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Russell, Conrad, “A Parliament in Early Stuart England,” in Tomlinson, Howard, ed.. Before the English Civil War (London, 1983), p. 138 n39Google Scholar is a brief response to Holmes.

3 Rogers, Nicholas, Whigs and Cities: Popular Politics in the Age of Walpole and Pitt (Oxford, 1989), esp. pp. 234, 256-57Google Scholar; see also Horwitz, Henry, “Party in a Civic Context: London from the Exclusion to the Fall of Walpole,” in Jones, Clyve, ed., Britain in the First Age of Party, 1680-1750: Essays presented to Geoffrey Holmes (London, 1987)Google Scholar.

4 Colley, Linda, In Defiance of Oligarchy (Cambridge, 1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 Cruikshanks, Eveline, Political Untouchables: The Tories and the '45 (London, 1979)Google Scholar.

6 Monod, Paul K., Jacobitism and the English People, 1688-1788 (Cambridge, 1989), p. 284Google Scholar.

7 The Growth of Political Stability, pp. 185-86.

8 Monod, , Jacobitism and the English People, pp. 348-49Google Scholar.

9 SirNamier, Lewis, England in the Age of the American Revolution (2nd ed.; London, 1961), p. 4Google Scholar.

10 Monod, , Jacobitism and the English People, p. 347Google Scholar; also Thompson, E. P., Whigs and Hunters: the Origin of the Black Act (New York, 1975)Google Scholar, and Harris, Michael, “Print and Politics in the Age of Walpole,” in Black, Jeremy, ed., Britain in the Age of Walpole (London, 1984), pp. 201, 202Google Scholar.

11 Colley, , In Defiance of Oligarchy, p. 20Google Scholar.

12 The Growth of Political Stability, pp. 172, xvii.

13 “The Growth of Political Stability Reconsidered,” p. 243.

14 The Growth of Political Stability, pp. 108, 101, 112, 116, 119, 120.

15 Brewer, John, The Sinews of Power (London, 1989), pp. 6667Google Scholar.

16 Holmes, Geoffrey, Augustan England: Professions, State and Society, 1680-1730 (London, 1982), pp. 240, 243-44, 256, 264, 274Google Scholar.

17 Brewer, , Sinews of Power, pp. xv, xvii-xviii, xxGoogle Scholar.

18 Boynton, Lindsay, The Elizabethan Militia, 1558-1638 (Toronto, 1967), pp. 166, 287Google Scholar; Williams, Philip, “The Crown and the Counties,” in Haigh, Christopher, ed., The Reign of Elizabeth I (Athens, Ga., 1985), pp. 130-31Google Scholar.

19 For the early Stuart Privy Council's supervision of local government, see Turner, Edward R., The Privy Council of England, 1603-1784, 2 vols. (Baltimore, 1927-1928), 1: ch. 7Google Scholar. For decline in the Privy Council's involvement with government, compare this chapter with that on the relation of the Privy Council to local government in the era after the Restoration (idem., 2: ch. 21).

20 Childs, John, The Army of Charles II (Toronto, 1976), pp. 5556Google Scholar. For the growth of the number of those served by Chelsea Hospital, and for Greenwich Hospital-established in the 1690s to care for sailors, see Joanna Innes, “The domestic face of the military-fiscal state: government and society in eighteenth-century Britain” (forthcoming in Lawrence Stone, ed., An Imperial State at War). I wish to thank Joanna Innes for sending me this essay in advance of publication.

21 Hughes, Edward, Studies in Administration and Finance, 1558-1825, with special reference to the history of salt taxation in England (1934; reprint London, 1980), p. 154Google Scholar; Beckett, J. V., “Land tax or Excise: the levying of taxation in seventeenth-and eighteenth-century England,” English Historical Review 100 (1985): 306Google Scholar; Brewer, , Sinews of Power, p. 98Google Scholar.

22 Landau, Norma, The Justices of the Peace, J679-1760 (Berkeley, 1984), pp. 69145Google Scholar; Glassey, Lionel K. J., Politics and the Appointment of Justices of the Peace, 1679-1720 (Oxford, 1979)Google Scholar.

23 Glassey, Lionel K. J., “Local Government,” in Jones, , Britain in the First Age of Party, pp. 169-70Google Scholar.

24 Turner, , The Privy Council of England, 2: 157, 416Google Scholar.

25 Henderson, Edith, The Foundations of English Administrative Law: Certiorari and Mandamus in the Seventeenth Century (Cambridge, Mass., 1963), pp. 2445CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 Ibid., p. 140. For the development of mandamus, see pp. 127-42; for the development of certiorari to quash, see pp. 143-59.

27 Innes, Joanna, “Parliament and the Shaping of Eighteenth-Century Social Policy,” Transactions of the Royal Historical Society 5th ser., 40 (1990): 6392CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

28 ibid., p. 89; and London Chronicle, March 8-10, 1774, pp. 239-40Google ScholarPubMed.

29 “The Growth of Political Stability Reconsidered,” p. 240.

30 Thompson, F. M. L., “The Social Distribution of Landed Property in England since the Sixteenth Century,” Economic History Review 2nd ser., 19 (1966): 510CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Ibid., p. 512, emphasis added.

32 Ibid.

33 Beckett, J. V., “English Landownership in the Later Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: the Debate and the Problems,” Economic History Review 2nd ser., 30 (1977): 569-70CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Roebuck, Peter, Yorkshire Baronets 1640-1760 (Oxford, 1980), p. 310Google Scholar; Howell, David, “Landlords and Estate Management in Wales,” in Thirsk, Joan, The Agrarian History of England and Wales. Vol. V: 1640-1750. II: Agrarian Change (London, 1985), p. 259Google Scholar; Clay, Christopher, “Property Settlements, Financial Provision for the Family, and Sale of Land by the Greater Landowners, 1660-1790,” Journal of British Studies 21 (1981): 38CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Clay, Christopher, “Landlords and Estate Management in England,” in Thirsk, The Agrarian History of England and Wales. Vol. V, p. 163, and see p. 169Google Scholar.

34 To some extent, Roberts's argument that patterns of landownership do not reveal a trend to oligarchy rests on evidence that non-aristocrats held large estates (and sometimes an increasing number of large estates). However, such evidence, which argues against the rise of “aristocracy,” can support an argument based on the rise of “oligarchy.”

35 “The Growth of Political Stability Reconsidered,” p. 240.

36 O'Gorman, Frank, Voters, Patrons and Parties: The Vnreformed Electoral System of Hanoverian England, 1734-1832 (Oxford, 1989), p. 179Google Scholar.

37 Rogers, , Whigs and Cities, pp. 230-31Google ScholarPubMed. O'Gorman, , Voters, Patrons and Parties, p. 100Google Scholar, which also shows that the 53 scot and lot boroughs also had an anomalously high rate of contested elections.

38 Ibid., p. 386.

39 Speck, W. A., “The Electorate in the First Age of Party,” in Jones, , Britain in the First Age of Party, pp. 4849Google Scholar; Speck, W. A. and Gray, W. A., “Computer Analysis of Poll Books: An Initial Report,” Bulletin of the Institute of Historical Research 43 (1970): 110CrossRefGoogle Scholar; W. A. Speck, W. A. Gray, and R. Hopkinson, “Computer Analysis of Poll Books: A Further Report,” ibid. 48 (1975): 69, 77, 83, 84, 86, 87-88; Phillips, John A., Electoral Behavior in Unreformed England: Plumpers, Splitters, and Straights (Princeton, 1982), pp. 9596Google Scholar.

40 Landau, Norma, “Independence, Deference, and Voter Participation: The Behaviour of the Electorate in Early-Eighteenth-Century Kent,” Historical Journal 22 (1979): 575-76, 566-67CrossRefGoogle Scholar; see also Speck, , “The Electorate in the First Age of Party,” p. 48Google Scholar, and Speck, , Gray, , and Hopkinson, , “Computer Analysis of Poll Books: A Further Report,” pp. 79-81, 83, 86Google Scholar. As O'Gorman's argument stresses the independence of the voter and the active participation of the electorate in the electoral process, it has to account for the phenomenon of the voter who appeared at only one election. His account explains such “casual” voting as an attribute of a mobile population (Voters, Patrons and Parties, p. 199). There are two problems with this explanation. First, the people whose mobility he cites are servants and apprentices, people who were very much more mobile than the adults who were voters (Kussmaul, Ann, “The Ambiguous Mobility of Farm Servants,” Economic History Review 2nd ser., 34 [1981]: 222-35CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Schofield, R. S., “Age-Specific Mobility in an Eighteenth Century Rural Parish,” Annates de Demographic Historique 1970 [1971]: 261-74)Google Scholar. For household mobility, see Laslett, Peter, Family Life and Illicit Love in Earlier Generations (Cambridge, 1977), p. 101CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Escott, Margaret M., “Residential Mobility in a late Eighteenth-Century Parish: Burfield, Berkshire 1779-1801,” Local Population Studies 40 (1988): 23Google Scholar. Secondly, the proportion of “casual” voters is much larger than that which could realistically be attributed to mobility. For instance, 4,676 of the 7,990 voters (59%) at the elections for Kent's county seats in September 1713 and February 1715 appeared at only one election. It is highly unlikely that 59 percent of Kent's voters had moved into or out of the county (or had purchased or sold a freehold in the county) in the eighteen months between elections.

41 Pocock, J. G. A., “The Classical Theory of Deference,” American Historical Review 81 (1976): 517-18, 521CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42 Pocock, J. G. A., “The Machiavellian Moment Revisited: A Study in History and Ideology,” Journal of Modern History 53 (1981): 50, and see p. 62CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 Pocock, J. G. A., Politics, Language and Time: Essays in Political Thought and History (New York, 1971)Google Scholar; idem., The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition (Princeton, 1975); idem., Virtue, Commerce, and History (Cambridge, 1985); Burtt, Shelley G., Virtue Transformed: Political Argument in England, 1688-1740 (Cambridge, 1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Skinner, Quentin, “The Principles and Practice of Opposition: The Case of Bolingbroke versus Walpole,” in McKendrick, Neil, ed., Historical Perspectives: Studies in English Thought and Society (London, 1974)Google Scholar; Hont, Istavon and Ignatieff, Michael, eds., Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment (Cambridge, 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dickinson, H. T., Liberty and Property: Political Ideology in Eighteenth-Century Britain (London, 1977)Google Scholar. In English Society, 1688-1832 (Cambridge, 1985)Google Scholar, J. C. D. Clark delineates an alternative paradigm for eighteenth-century thought, a paradigm presented as appropriate for the thought of a society Clark labels “ancien regime.” According to Clark, the “essential characteristics” of this society were: “it was Anglican, it was aristocratic, and it was monarchical” (p. 7). However, the thought that Clark delineates does not give equal attention to monarchy, aristocracy, and Anglicanism. Instead, his paradigm emphasizes Trinitarian Protestant support for divine right monarchy. Therefore, it does not adumbrate that framework of ideas which justified the existence of an oligarchy so powerful that it constrained monarchy.

44 Pocock, J. G. A., “Machiavelli, Harrington, and English Political Ideologies in the Eighteenth Century,” William and Mary Quarterly 3rd series, 22 (1965): 556-62, 567-70CrossRefGoogle Scholar, reprinted in Politics, Language and Time.

45 For example, Plumb, , The Growth of Political Stability, pp. 146-47, 140, 132, 151Google Scholar.

46 The Growth of Political Stability, pp. 3-8, 24-26.